Sunday, December 14, 2014

Oil


The most important thing is this (oil price collapse) is a massive tax cut for the world. This is really good stuff for the world.

Larry Fink
CEO Blackrock
December 11, 2014


Lower oil prices are like a tax cut to the economy, so in terms of macroeconomic impact, it’s a positive.

Jacob Lew
U.S. Treasury Secretary
December 11, 2014


Despite the impressive recent gains in natural gas and crude oil production, the U.S. is still a net importer of energy. As a result, falling energy prices are beneficial for our economy.

Over the near term, this will lead to a significant rise in real income growth for households and should be a strong spur to consumer spending. Since energy expenditures represent a higher proportion of outlays for lower income households, falling energy prices disproportionately raise their real incomes. Also, because such households are more liquidity constrained, with budgets that often bind paycheck to paycheck, they have a higher tendency to spend any additional real income.

As a result, much of the boost to real household income from falling energy prices is likely to be spent, not saved.

Bill Dudley
President New York Federal Reserve Bank
December 1, 2014


Here we have the head of the world’s largest asset manager, the CFO of the U.S. government and the globe’s chief money printer and regulator of the world’s most important banks all telling us that crashing oil prices are a good thing. Consumption will go up and savings will fall as a result of lower oil prices and these are, allegedly, good things.

Personally, I have never seen an issue that more starkly contrasts the Keynesian view of the world, as referenced above, with that of the Austrians.   

Keynesians focus on GDP, aggregate demand and animal spirits. Austrians focus on savings and capital creation, the entrepreneur’s focus on wealth creation and the avoidance of the malinvestment that comes from money and credit creation from thin air.

Keynesians want to boost consumption and penalize savings following a bust by artificially pushing interest rates lower. Austrians want to point to rates being too low during the bubble phase as being the cause of the subsequent crash and economic hangover and they argue that lower rates for longer will only create bigger problems in the future.

Oil’s collapse gives us a perfect perch from which to compare these contrasting economic views.

As we saw above, the typical Keynesian view is that the oil price collapse should increase consumer demand and decrease savings. These are thought to be good things.

Austrians view the oil price collapse with horror. Savings (real capital) was wasted on a truly epic scale as malinvestment ran amok throughout one the world’s biggest and most important industries. This is an industry that has seen annual upstream capital expenditures increase by about 75% to nearly $700 billion in the past five years. Pretty much all of that spending appears to have been wasted.

How could this happen?

Keynesians, it seems, don’t really care about the cause of all of this wasted capital. In the U.S. and Europe the only concern seems to be with whether or not the oil price collapse will lead to increased consumption and decreased savings. Both of these effects are cheered on by the Keynesians.

Austrians point to artificially low interest rates as having impacted the structure of production and consumption. Artificially low rates appear to have been a prime mover in China’s titanic infrastructure build-out of the past five years. This created a nearly insatiable demand for energy on the part of China, the major incremental driver of nearly everything on the planet for much of the recent past. This demand drove oil prices relentlessly higher over the past few years.

Alas, the Chinese real estate miracle appears to have crested and, with real estate prices starting to fall, the infrastructure build-out has stalled. Energy demand is, therefore, falling relative to previous expectations.

Oil production, especially in the U.S., boomed with the rise in capital spending that came from artificially low interest rates and strong, but artificial, oil demand. Despite the overall fall in savings in the U.S. over the past decade, whatever remained of the pool of savings was made available for oil production. In fact, oil production in the U.S. is up about 80% from its low point and the high yield market has come to be dominated by borrowers from the oil patch.

To the Austrians, looking back at the oil boom, it was lots of money and credit from thin air that drove the malinvestment that is now being revealed. They question whether pushing the savings rate lower from the current miniscule levels, a move that the Keynesians cheer, will allow for adequate capital spending in the future to drive any wealth creation in the U.S. They also worry about why anyone would ever want to create and deploy capital (savings) any longer if it always seems to be wasted. Malinvestment is simply a reduction in the already paltry rate of interest that is currently being paid on savings and it does not bode well for future capital creation or future real GDP growth.

Until recently, everyone thought that increased U.S. oil production would lead to American energy independence and that this was a good thing. Now, it seems like the Keynesians are telling us that wasting a few trillion dollars in the oil patch while blowing up the junk bond market was also a good thing. Who knew?

I’ll stick with the Austrian line: The crash in oil prices is exposing malinvestment that was driven by central bank fostered easy money policies which destroyed wealth, deters future savings and wealth creation and, as a result, destroys future growth opportunities.

Disclaimer: Nothing on this site should be construed as investment advice. It is all merely the opinion of the author.

Monday, December 8, 2014

Gold


My previous post was on the inevitable failure of fiat currencies. It seems then as if this might be an appropriate moment to spend some time on the subject of gold.
Rarely has there ever been an asset class as hated as the yellow metal. Economists (outside of the Austrians) despise it. After all, its use as money would certainly eliminate any need for us to have them opine on the proper level of interest rates and how much money and credit should be whipped up from thin air. Gold as money would remove economists from the biggest part of the public policy debate, and this is unimaginable in their eyes. How would the free market ever decide on the proper level of interest rates? Chaos would surely ensue without their learned input.

While there are many essays out there dismissing gold as an investment and its use as money, I want to focus on one particular issue that Keynesians have been harping on for years. It seems that many economists do not like it that gold is expensive to mine and expensive to store. Surely this is waste of society’s capital:
Most of all, the barrenness of this proposal (i.e., to use gold) makes it most repugnant to those who think that the international need for liquidity can be put to better use than the financing digging gold from the entrails of the earth and reburying it in the vaults of Fort Knox and other gold graves.

Robert Triffin (1957)

Recently, Citibank economist Willem Buiter made the same argument against gold:
Gold is unlike any other commodity. It is costly to extract from the earth and to refine to a reasonable degree of purity. It is costly to store….The cost and waste involved in getting it out of the ground only to put it back back under ground in secure vaults is considerable.

The argument, as you can see, hasn’t changed much over the past six decades. It even makes a certain amount of intuitive sense.  Unfortunately, for the Keynesians, the argument fails when examined in just a little more detail.

I am not going to claim that gold isn’t costly to mine. At $1200/oz., the value of the gold mined each year is equivalent to about $110 billion, and that isn’t chump change. Better to use unbacked fiat money, which costs nothing to produce, according to most economists.
Well, from the Austrian standpoint, it costs society quite a bit to use unbacked fiat money. ABCT presumes that money and credit creation from thin air creates malinvestment. While the cost is somewhat difficult to calculate precisely, it is easily in the multiple trillions of dollars per year. How much malinvestment was revealed as technology shares crashed in 2000-2001? How much malinvestment came to light in the real estate debacle of 2008? How much malinvestment is now being revealed as emerging market carry trades unwind, Chinese (and London) real estate slumps and as oil prices plunge. Trillions upon trillions of dollars have been wasted. Gold’s burden is fairly light then relative to the costs we are piling up elsewhere due to the use of unbacked fiat money.

Unbacked fiat money also has another problem: It violates the principle that all transactions require a like-for-like exchange. All parties need to believe that they are made better off in a transaction. If you produce apples and I produce oranges, we may both be better off if we exchange some of our output. This betterment principle is violated when money and credit is created from thin air. Someone gets something for nothing. The original parties will undertake the transaction, but only because they believe that they can pass on the burden to someone else before the theft has been revealed. Some Austrians have compared the effects of inflation (the creation of money and credit from thin air) to a train since some cars arrive in the station before others. Often, fixed income investors and pensioners are at the back of the train and bear the bulk of the costs associated with the inflation brought on by the use of unbacked fiat money. Unbacked fiat money violates this like-for-like principle while gold does not.
Unbacked fiat money is nothing but theft. It sets in motion malinvestment and it violates the like-for-like principle. It carries huge, but hidden, costs and it has always, eventually, failed and been rejected by the public. I doubt this time will be any different. Mr. Buiter referred to gold as a 6000 year bubble, and perhaps this true. I am certain, however, that no unbacked fiat currency will ever establish such a record. Yes, gold may not return as money, but something will replace unbacked fiat. Nevertheless, I believe that finding something better than gold as money will be most difficult.
Disclaimer: Nothing on this site should be construed as investment advice. It is all merely the opinion of the author.