In what I found to be a most
interesting article, Jared Bernstein, a former Obama and Joe Biden economic
adviser, wrote an op-ed in the New York Times advocating the removal of the
U.S. dollar as the world’s reserve currency.
He claims that the balance of
payment deficit engendered by the dollar’s reserve status is costing the U.S.
jobs. These job losses are the result of foreign demand to hold the reserve
currency, pushing the dollar too high relative to other currencies making
production in the U.S. too costly. He reckons that the downside of losing
reserve status for the dollar would be an increase of just 1% in the CPI rate
of inflation. This, he thought, would be
an acceptable, low cost, trade off.
As someone who thinks that
the U.S. would experience acute pain from seeing the dollar lose its reserve
status, I thought that I should attempt to explain why I feel this way.
Let me start by referencing
another article that I found to be most fascinating over at Mises.org.
Dante Bayona referenced an
old tale about Salvador Dali:
It was a good deal for Dali: his checks never came back to the bank to be cashed, and he still enjoyed great banquets with all of his friends. Dali had a magic checkbook.
But what would have happened if one day art collectors concluded that Dali’s work really did not capture the essence of surrealism, and therefore that his art was not of great value? If that had happened, every autographed check would have come back to the bank (at least in theory), and Dali would have had to pay up. If Dali had not saved enough money, he would have had to find a job painting houses.
Bayona, in using this story, is warning
that the U.S. has been writing an excessive number of checks that it clearly
believes will never be cashed. As long as the dollar remains the world’s
reserve currency those dollar-based IOUs held overseas will remain there,
uncashed.
But just what would happen if
the dollar lost its reserve status and those checks had to be honored? I
propose that we look at a similar situation that played out for the U.S.
between the end of WW II and, roughly, 1980.
By way of quick background,
in 1944 the world agreed to adopt the Bretton-Woods monetary system. Everyone
agreed that both dollars and gold would be counted as reserves. The U.S., at
the time possessing something on the order of 70% of the world’s monetary gold,
would see its currency and IOUs held by foreigners, counted as official
reserves. The U.S. also promised to honor a gold exchange ratio for foreigners
of $35/oz. and currency ratios would all be fixed.
The one thing that no one
counted on at Bretton-Woods was the idea that the U.S. could start to run
balance of payment deficits. After all, the U.S. was going to emerge from WW II
as the economic colossus of the globe. It was impossible to imagine the U.S. as
an emerging debtor, but that is exactly what happened.
U.S. U.S.
Short Term Liabilities Gold Stock
Year to Foreigners @$35/Oz. Tonnes
1955 $11,895 $21,753 19,331
1960 $18,701 $17,804 15,822
1965 $25,551 $13,806 12,268
1968 $31,717 $10,892 9,679
1971 * $55,417 $10,206 9,069
1974 * $95,000 $11,803 10,489
($ in millions)
* Bretton-Woods gold conversion was abandoned in 1968
and gold was then no longer fixed at $35/oz.
Source: The War on Gold,
Anthony Sutton, 1977
As we can see above, the U.S.
had managed to accumulate debts to foreigners of $18.7 billion by 1960, and
this was after settling a further $3.5 billion in foreign claims by shipping
3,500 tonnes of gold overseas. That is, dollars were starting to flow back towards the U.S. The checks that the U.S. had written, never expecting them to be cashed, were being presented for payment.
The problem was that by 1960,
the U.S. no longer had enough gold, if valued at $35/oz., to settle its debts
to foreigners. The U.S. either had to revalue gold higher (a default), continue
to ship gold overseas or adjust its economy so that is ceased allowing
excessive money and credit growth so that the gold outflow was stemmed.
For a time, until 1968, the
U.S. chose to stay the course, to continue to allow excessive money and credit
growth and to cap the gold price at $35.
Foreigners during this period
continued to send dollars back to the U.S. in exchange for gold even as dollar
claims to foreigners continued to explode due to easy money policies in the
U.S.
By 1968 it was clear to the
U.S. that they were about to lose all of their gold and they defaulted on their
obligations, refusing to honor the $35/oz. pledge of Bretton-Woods. By 1971, the
fixed currency portion of Bretton-Woods was also ended, burying the
Bretton-Woods system forever.
In 1960, the first year where
U.S. obligations to foreigners exceeded its gold holdings, the U.S. GDP figure
was $543 billion. The foreign obligations of the U.S. then amounted to just 3.4%
of GDP. This was enough to destroy the monetary system of the day.
By 1974, with inflation
picking up, U.S. GDP had nearly tripled to $1,548 billion and foreign
liabilities had jumped to 6.1% of GDP.
Between 1955 and the end of
the U.S. honoring its $35/oz. gold obligation, foreigners sent back well over
$11 billion dollars to the U.S., and this clearly intensified inflationary
pressures in the U.S.
In the following graph we can
see that post WW II the velocity of money in the economy started to accelerate, particularly after 1955:
Part of the increase was initially driven by a normalization of the economy following the war, but the acceleration in velocity was increasingly driven, in my opinion, by the loss of confidence in the dollar's reserve status.
As the dollar started to lose
its reserve currency status and dollars that were expected to remain overseas
permanently flowed back to the U.S., CPI inflation picked up dramatically as a consequence of the increase in velocity. From a sub 2% rate in the late 1950s, CPI inflation was
over 6% by 1969 before completely exploding in the 1970s.
My point is that foreign
obligations of somewhere between 3-6% of GDP created, in the end, massive
CPI inflationary problems as many of the dollars flowed back to the U.S. Faith, of
course, wasn’t just lost by foreigners, it merely kick started the process of a
loss of confidence in the dollar inside the U.S. as well, forcing velocity and
CPI inflation much higher.
I would stress that the
imbalances of the Bretton-Woods period pale in comparison to the imbalances
created by the reckless monetary policies of the Fed and other central banks of
the past couple of decades.
The IMF’s Composition of
Foreign Exchange report (COFER) alone details nearly $12 trillion of foreign exchange reserves held
by global monetary authorities. Perhaps 60% of this is held in U.S. dollars,
roughly $7 trillion. This amounts to 40% of current GDP for the U.S. The Fed’s
balance sheet now stands at 26% of GDP. These numbers dwarf the imbalances that
kicked off a flow of overseas dollars back to the U.S. under Bretton-Woods, resulting
in the start of CPI inflation in the 1960s.
More importantly, Russia and
China appear to have been forced by U.S. actions in the form of inconsequential
returns on their dollar based holdings and interference in their historical
spheres of influence to push for a removal of the dollar from center of the
global economy. This just may give Mr. Bernstein his wish, the removal of the
dollar as the world’s reserve currency.
Unfortunately, unlike
Salvador Dali’s experience, the checks that the U.S. has written over the
years, checks they expected to never see cashed due to the dollar’s reserve
status, will come home again. The result should be massively higher CPI
inflation. Dali actually provided those who took his checks with something of
great value in the form of his art. The U.S. cannot say the same as its current
rate of savings and growth in output cannot hope to cover the number of checks
it has been writing.
It won’t be pleasant as it
happens, but such an outcome is a necessary precursor to returning to sustainable
growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment